The Misconception of Scarcity
Economic Articles
Submit Articles Back to Articles
My love as deep; the more I give to thee,
The more I have, for both are infinite.
(William Shakespeare, Romeo and Juliet, Act 2, Scene 2)
Are we confronted merely with a bear market in stocks - or is it
the first phase of a global contraction of the magnitude of the Great
Depression? The answer overwhelmingly depends on how we understand scarcity.
It will be only a mild overstatement to say that the science of
economics, such as it is, revolves around the Malthusian concept of scarcity.
Our infinite wants, the finiteness of our resources and the bad job we too often
make of allocating them efficiently and optimally - lead to mismatches between
supply and demand. We are forever forced to choose between opportunities,
between alternative uses of resources, painfully mindful of their costs.
This is how the perennial textbook "Economics" (seventeenth
edition), authored by Nobel prizewinner Paul Samuelson and William Nordhaus,
defines the dismal science:
"Economics is the study of how societies use scarce resources to
produce valuable commodities and distribute them among different people."
The classical concept of scarcity - unlimited wants vs. limited
resources - is lacking. Anticipating much-feared scarcity encourages hoarding
which engenders the very evil it was meant to fend off. Ideas and knowledge -
inputs as important as land and water - are not subject to scarcity, as work
done by Nobel laureate Robert Solow and, more importantly, by Paul Romer, an
economist from the University of California at Berkeley, clearly demonstrates.
Additionally, it is useful to distinguish natural from synthetic resources.
The scarcity of most natural resources (a type of
"external scarcity") is only theoretical at present. Granted, many resources are
unevenly distributed and badly managed. But this is man-made ("internal")
scarcity and can be undone by Man. It is truer to assume, for practical
purposes, that most natural resources - when not egregiously abused and when
freely priced - are infinite rather than scarce. The anthropologist Marshall
Sahlins discovered that primitive peoples he has studied had no concept of
"scarcity" - only of "satiety". He called them the first "affluent societies".
This is because, fortunately, the number of people on
Earth is finite - and manageable - while most resources can either be
replenished or substituted. Alarmist claims to the contrary by environmentalists
have been convincingly debunked by the likes of Bjorn Lomborg, author of "The
Skeptical Environmentalist".
Equally, it is true that manufactured goods, agricultural
produce, money, and services are scarce. The number of industrialists, service
providers, or farmers is limited - as is their life span. The quantities of raw
materials, machinery and plant are constrained. Contrary to classic economic
teaching, human wants are limited - only so many people exist at any given time
and not all them desire everything all the time. But, even so, the demand for
man-made goods and services far exceeds the supply.
Scarcity is the attribute of a "closed" economic universe. But
it can be alleviated either by increasing the supply of goods and services (and
human beings) - or by improving the efficiency of the allocation of economic
resources. Technology and innovation are supposed to achieve the former -
rational governance, free trade, and free markets the latter.
The telegraph, the telephone, electricity, the train, the car,
the agricultural revolution, information technology and, now, biotechnology have
all increased our resources, seemingly ex nihilo. This multiplication of
wherewithal falsified all apocalyptic Malthusian scenarios hitherto. Operations
research, mathematical modeling, transparent decision making, free trade, and
professional management - help better allocate these increased resources to
yield optimal results.
Markets are supposed to regulate scarcity by storing information
about our wants and needs. Markets harmonize supply and demand. They do so
through the price mechanism. Money is, thus, a unit of information and a
conveyor or conduit of the price signal - as well as a store of value and a
means of exchange.
Markets and scarcity are intimately related. The former would be
rendered irrelevant and unnecessary in the absence of the latter. Assets
increase in value in line with their scarcity - i.e., in line with either
increasing demand or decreasing supply. When scarcity decreases - i.e., when
demand drops or supply surges - asset prices collapse. When a resource is
thought to be infinitely abundant (e.g., air) - its price is zero.
Armed with these simple and intuitive observations, we can now
survey the dismal economic landscape.
The abolition of scarcity was a pillar of the paradigm shift to
the "new economy". The marginal costs of producing and distributing intangible
goods, such as intellectual property, are negligible. Returns increase - rather
than decrease - with each additional copy. An original software retains its
quality even if copied numerous times. The very distinction between "original"
and "copy" becomes obsolete and meaningless. Knowledge products are "non-rival
goods" (i.e., can be used by everyone simultaneously).
Such ease of replication gives rise to network effects and
awards first movers with a monopolistic or oligopolistic position. Oligopolies
are better placed to invest excess profits in expensive research and development
in order to achieve product differentiation. Indeed, such firms justify charging
money for their "new economy" products with the huge sunken costs they incur -
the initial expenditures and investments in research and development, machine
tools, plant, and branding.
To sum, though financial and human resources as well as content
may have remained scarce - the quantity of intellectual property goods is
potentially infinite because they are essentially cost-free to reproduce.
Plummeting production costs also translate to enhanced productivity and wealth
formation. It looked like a virtuous cycle.
But the abolition of scarcity implied the abolition of value.
Value and scarcity are two sides of the same coin. Prices reflect scarcity.
Abundant products are cheap. Infinitely abundant products - however useful - are
complimentary. Consider money. Abundant money - an intangible commodity - leads
to depreciation against other currencies and inflation at home. This is why
central banks intentionally foster money scarcity.
But if intellectual property goods are so abundant and cost-free
- why were distributors of intellectual property so valued, not least by
investors in the stock exchange? Was it gullibility or ignorance of basic
economic rules?
Not so. Even "new economists" admitted to temporary shortages
and "bottlenecks" on the way to their utopian paradise of cost-free abundance.
Demand always initially exceeds supply. Internet backbone capacity, software
programmers, servers are all scarce to start with - in the old economy sense.
This scarcity accounts for the stratospheric erstwhile
valuations of dotcoms and telecoms. Stock prices were driven by projected
ever-growing demand and not by projected ever-growing supply of
asymptotically-free goods and services. "The Economist" describes how WorldCom
executives flaunted the cornucopian doubling of Internet traffic every 100 days.
Telecoms predicted a tsunami of clients clamoring for G3 wireless Internet
services. Electronic publishers gleefully foresaw the replacement of the print
book with the much heralded e-book.
The irony is that the new economy self-destructed because most
of its assumptions were spot on. The bottlenecks were, indeed, temporary.
Technology, indeed, delivered near-cost-free products in endless quantities.
Scarcity was, indeed, vanquished.
Per the same cost, the amount of information one can transfer
through a single fiber optic swelled 100 times. Computer storage catapulted
80,000 times. Broadband and cable modems let computers communicate at 300 times
their speed only 5 years ago. Scarcity turned to glut. Demand failed to catch up
with supply. In the absence of clear price signals - the outcomes of scarcity -
the match between the two went awry.
One innovation the "new economy" has wrought is "inverse
scarcity" - unlimited resources (or products) vs. limited wants. Asset exchanges
the world over are now adjusting to this harrowing realization - that cost free
goods are worth little in terms of revenues and that people are badly disposed
to react to zero marginal costs.
The new economy caused a massive disorientation and dislocation
of the market and the price mechanism. Hence the asset bubble. Reverting to an
economy of scarcity is our only hope. If we don't do so deliberately - the
markets will do it for us, mercilessly.
A Comment on "Manufactured Scarcity"
Conspiracy theorists have long alleged that manufacturers foster
scarcity by building into their products mechanisms of programmed obsolescence
and apopstosis (self-destruction). But scarcity is artificially manufactured in
less obvious (and far less criminal) ways.
Technological advances, product revisions, new features, and
novel editions render successive generations of products obsolete. Consumerism
encourages owners to rid themselves of their possessions and replace them with
newer, more gleaming, status-enhancing substitutes offered by design departments
and engineering workshops worldwide. Cherished values of narcissistic
competitiveness and malignant individualism play an important socio-cultural
role in this semipternal game of musical chairs.
Many products have a limited shelf life or an expiry date
(rarely supported by solid and rigorous research). They are to be promptly
disposed of and, presumably, instantaneously replaced with new ones.
Finally, manufacturers often knowingly produce scarcity by
limiting their output or by restricting access to their goods. "Limited
editions" of works of art and books are prime examples of this stratagem.
About the Author
Sam Vaknin is the author of "Malignant Self Love - Narcissism Revisited" and
"After the Rain - How the West Lost the East". He is a columnist in "Central
Europe Review", United Press International (UPI) and ebookweb.org and the editor
of mental health and Central East Europe categories in The Open Directory,
Suite101 and searcheurope.com. Until recently, he served as the Economic Advisor
to the Government of Macedonia.
His web site: http://samvak.tripod.com
Follow us @Scopulus_News
Article Published/Sorted/Amended on Scopulus 2007-11-04 00:08:13 in Economic Articles